Chicken Game Nash Equilibria: How Many?

how many nash equilibria are there in this chicken game

The Chicken Game is a classic example of a strategic interaction where the outcome depends on the choices of both players. In this game, two drivers speed towards each other, and the first one to 'chicken out' and swerve away loses. The game ends in a crash if neither driver swerves. The players must decide whether to swerve or stay on course, with the latter being the best response to the former, and vice versa. A Nash equilibrium is a set of strategies where neither player has an incentive to change their strategy based on the actions of the other player. In the Chicken Game, there are two pure-strategy Nash equilibria: one where one player stays on course while the other swerves, and the other where the players' roles are reversed. There is also a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium where both players swerve with a probability of 2/3 and do not swerve with a probability of 1/3.

Characteristics Values
Number of Nash Equilibria 2
First Equilibrium Player 1 stays the course, Player 2 swerves
Second Equilibrium Player 1 swerves, Player 2 stays the course
Non-Equilibrium Both players adopt the same strategy
Game Structure Two players drive towards each other, first to swerve loses
Payoff Structure If one player swerves and the other doesn't, the non-swerver gets +1 and the swerver gets -1
If both players swerve, both get 0
If neither player swerves, both get -100
Optimal Strategy Build a credible reputation for fearlessness and unpredictability
Mixed-Strategy Equilibrium Both players swerve with probability 2/3 and do not swerve with probability 1/3

cychicken

Pure strategy Nash equilibria

A Nash equilibrium is a set of strategies where no player has an incentive to change their strategy based on the actions of other players. In the Chicken game, two players face each other in cars moving at extremely high speed. The player who swerves first becomes the "chicken" and gets -1 point, while the other player gets +1 for not swerving. If both players swerve, they each get 0 points, and if neither swerves, both cars crash, and they each get -100 points.

The Chicken game has three Nash equilibria, two of which are pure strategy equilibria. In the first pure strategy Nash equilibrium, one player swerves (Dove/Chicken) while the other does not (Hawk/Straight). This is because the player who swerves first ("Chicken") would not want to change their strategy and get 0 points instead of -1, and the player who does not swerve first ("Hawk") would not want to change their strategy and get 0 points instead of +1. This equilibrium is based on mutual trust and cooperation, as both players must trust that the other will act in a way that avoids the worst-case scenario of a crash.

The second pure strategy Nash equilibrium occurs when both players decide to swerve (Dove/Chicken). In this case, neither player wants to change their strategy because swerving results in a better outcome than not swerving, which leads to a crash. This equilibrium is based on mutual avoidance of the worst-case scenario, ensuring that neither player ends up with the worst outcome.

It's important to note that the Chicken game is a simplified model, and real-world strategic interactions may involve more complex factors, such as incomplete information, sequential moves, and dynamic payoffs. However, the concept of Nash equilibria remains a fundamental tool for analyzing and predicting outcomes in game theory and strategic decision-making.

cychicken

Mixed strategy Nash equilibria

The Chicken Game is a classic example of a strategic interaction where the outcome depends on the choices of both players. In this game, two players in separate cars face each other, moving at extremely high speeds. The player who swerves first loses and gets -1 points, while the other player gets +1 for not swerving first. If both players swerve, they each get 0 points, and if neither player swerves, both cars crash, resulting in a score of -100 for both players.

A Nash equilibrium is a set of strategies where no player has an incentive to change their strategy based on the actions of the other players. In the context of the Chicken Game, there are two pure strategy Nash equilibria:

  • Player A stays on course while Player B swerves away.
  • Player B stays on course while Player A swerves away.

In both scenarios, neither player has a reason to change their strategy because swerving is the best response to the other player staying on course, and vice versa. However, if both players employ the same strategy, it is not a Nash equilibrium because each player believes they can gain a higher payoff by changing their approach.

Now, let's focus on mixed strategy Nash equilibria in the Chicken Game:

In a mixed strategy, players choose to swerve or not swerve with certain probabilities. For instance, Player A might choose to swerve with a probability of 0.5 and not swerve with a probability of 0.5, while Player B does the same. This type of strategy can be optimal if it makes the opposing player indifferent between their choices, resulting in the same expected payoff, regardless of whether they swerve or not.

In the Chicken Game, a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium exists where both players choose to swerve with a probability of 2/3 and not swerve with a probability of 1/3. This equilibrium is different from both players choosing to swerve or not swerve with a probability of 1/2, which would result in an expected payoff of 1.5. By choosing to swerve 2/3 of the time and not swerve 1/3 of the time, players can achieve an expected payoff of 2, which is the highest possible payoff in the game.

At this mixed strategy Nash equilibrium, if a player were to consider changing their strategy, they would find that their expected payoff remains the same. For example, let's consider Player A again. If Player A were to change their strategy and choose to swerve with a probability of 0.6 and not swerve with a probability of 0.4 instead, their expected payoff would still be calculated as:

Expected payoff for swerving = 2q (where q is the probability that Player B will swerve)

Expected payoff for not swerving = 3q + 1 (where q is still the probability that Player B will swerve)

Given that Player B is at the same mixed strategy Nash equilibrium, their probability of swerving is 2/3, so:

Expected payoff for swerving = 2(2/3) = 4/3

Expected payoff for not swerving = 3(2/3) + 1 = 7/3

As you can see, both expected payoffs are equal to 2, which is the same payoff Player A would achieve by sticking to the original mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Therefore, Player A has no incentive to change their strategy, and the same logic applies to Player B. This indifference to changing strategies is a key characteristic of a Nash equilibrium.

cychicken

Building a credible reputation

The game of chicken is a strategic interaction where the outcome depends on the choices of both players. In this game, two players drive towards each other on a collision course, and the first one to swerve loses. The game is often associated with brinkmanship, where players make strategic moves to prevent their opponent from becoming aggressive.

Adopting an optimal strategy: This involves building a reputation for fearlessness, projecting an unwavering resolve to not swerve, and introducing unpredictability into decision-making. By establishing a reputation for determination and maintaining unpredictability, you can convince your opponent that you are the riskier player, increasing the likelihood of them swerving to avoid a collision.

Knowing your opponent: It is important to understand who you are playing against and how much they have to lose if they back down. This knowledge can help you assess their potential moves and adjust your strategy accordingly.

Understanding your own stakes: Before engaging in the game of chicken, it is crucial to evaluate what you stand to lose and how much you have invested. This self-awareness can guide your decisions and help you determine if the potential rewards outweigh the risks.

Flexibility as a weakness: In the context of the game of chicken, flexibility or the willingness to compromise can be seen as a weakness. Maintaining a rigid stance and sticking to your chosen strategy may increase your chances of success. However, it is important to note that this approach carries significant risks, especially in situations where both players refuse to yield.

Reputation and brinkmanship: In some cases, building a credible reputation involves brinkmanship, where you make calculated moves to showcase your commitment to a particular course of action. This strategy aims to increase the perceived risk of confrontation and incentivize your opponent to back down. However, brinkmanship is a delicate tactic that carries the risk of escalating the conflict if not employed skillfully.

Using threats and raising the stakes: In certain situations, you can alter the payoffs or consequences associated with "swerving" or yielding. This can involve making explicit threats or raising the stakes to signal your determination and the potential costs of not conceding to your demands. However, this approach requires careful consideration, as it can lead to heightened tensions and unintended consequences.

cychicken

Creating a 'last clear chance'

To create a 'last clear chance' in the Chicken game, you need to understand the concept of Nash Equilibrium, which is a set of strategies where no player has an incentive to change their approach based on the actions of their opponent. In the Chicken game, the Nash Equilibria are when one player swerves away while the other stays on course, resulting in a payoff of 0 for the one who swerves and +1 for the one who stays.

  • Understand the Payoffs: In the Chicken game, the payoffs for different scenarios are crucial. If both players swerve, they each get 0. If one player swerves and the other stays, the swerving player gets 0, and the staying player gets +1. However, if both players stay on course, they will eventually crash, resulting in a worst-case scenario of -100 points for both.
  • Commit to 'Staying the Course': To create a 'last clear chance,' you must commit to 'staying the course' and not swerving. This commitment serves as a signal to your opponent, providing them with a clear opportunity to change their strategy and swerve away.
  • Leverage Reputation and Expectations: As Thomas Schelling notes, the game of Chicken often involves reputation, status, and expectations. You can use this to your advantage by signalling that you value your 'face' or reputation highly and are willing to take risks to maintain it. This may influence your opponent's perception and encourage them to swerve away to avoid mutual destruction.
  • Consider the Opponent's Rationality: The success of creating a 'last clear chance' relies on the assumption that your opponent is rational about their self-preservation. They must recognize that if they swerve away, they can avoid the worst-case scenario of a crash and still obtain a better outcome than if they stay on course.
  • Communicate Your Commitment: Ensure that your opponent is aware of your commitment to 'staying the course'. This can be done through explicit communication or by signalling your intentions through actions or other means. A rational opponent should then realize that their best response is to swerve away to avoid the worst-case scenario and minimize losses.
  • Anticipate Your Opponent's Move: As you create a 'last clear chance,' anticipate your opponent's likely response. They may choose to swerve away to avoid the crash, in which case you will obtain a positive outcome (+1) while they receive 0. However, be prepared for the possibility that they may also choose to stay on course, especially if they believe you will swerve at the last moment.

By following these steps and considerations, you can create a 'last clear chance' in the game of Chicken, increasing your chances of a favourable outcome. This strategy leverages the concept of Nash Equilibrium and the understanding that mutual destruction is not in either player's best interest.

cychicken

Incentive to change strategies

The Chicken Game is a classic example of conflict in microeconomics, rooted in game theory, where two players drive towards each other on a collision course. The first player to swerve away and avoid a crash is considered a "chicken" or a coward. This game is used to illustrate situations where mutual destruction is possible unless one party concedes or compromises.

In the Chicken Game, each player has two choices: continue on their path (a willful decision) or swerve (a yielding decision). The outcome depends on the choices of both players, and the potential payoffs vary depending on the actions of each player.

A Nash equilibrium occurs when both players choose strategies that maximize their own payoff given their opponent's strategy, resulting in neither player benefiting from changing their decision. In the Chicken Game, there are typically two Nash equilibria where one player swerves while the other continues.

Incentives to change strategies are influenced by the desire to avoid the worst-case scenario, which is both players continuing and resulting in a "head-on collision" with the lowest payoff. Both players have an equal incentive to change their strategies and avoid this outcome.

Additionally, players may consider altering the payoffs associated with "swerving away." For example, in a game between nations, exhibiting combativeness when the other shows restraint may be desirable for domestic political reasons. However, if both nations are combative, they risk total war. In this scenario, the incentive to change strategies lies in creating a "last clear chance" for the adversary to "swerve away," turning a simultaneous game into a sequential one.

Another factor influencing the incentive to change strategies is the perception of the opponent's aggressiveness or risk aversion. If a player believes their opponent is more aggressive, they may be less inclined to swerve, and vice versa.

Furthermore, in a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium, each player must be willing to mix, which means being indifferent between swerving and not swerving. If a player can gain a higher payoff by committing to one strategy over the other, they may have an incentive to change their strategy.

While game theory provides a framework for understanding the Chicken Game, it's important to note that it doesn't make specific recommendations. Instead, it offers predictions based on assumptions and the rationality of the players.

Frequently asked questions

Written by
Reviewed by
Share this post
Print
Did this article help you?

Leave a comment